Guest views are now limited to 12 pages. If you get an "Error" message, just sign in! If you need to create an account, click here.

Jump to content
  • CRYPTO REWARDS!

    Full endorsement on this opportunity - but it's limited, so get in while you can!

Did the FED buy $5.5T IQD???


frankc
 Share

Recommended Posts

Is it true? Did the FED buy $5.5T IQD??? If they did buy dinar and anything close to that number it is a huge validation an RV is coming.

They didnt buy it.....they have had 4 to 5 trillion dinar in the federal reserve for a long time now and they have it there to earn interest for Iraq.....but of course it should help strengthen the US dollar when it RV's.....

  • Upvote 1
  • Downvote 1
Link to comment
Share on other sites

They didnt buy it.....they have had 4 to 5 trillion dinar in the federal reserve for a long time now and they have it there to earn interest for Iraq.....but of course it should help strengthen the US dollar when it RV's.....

Is it our money or Iraq's? What was behind wanting to earn interest for Iraq? Do you think "W" knew all the time there would be an RV because that was always the plan? Thx

Link to comment
Share on other sites

They didnt buy it.....they have had 4 to 5 trillion dinar in the federal reserve for a long time now and they have it there to earn interest for Iraq.....but of course it should help strengthen the US dollar when it RV's.....

Actually, the Fed Reserve Bank of NY "owns" these Dinar! G W Bush signed a Presidential Order in 2004 enabling the Fed to buy, using US Dollars these Dinar from the GOI. This is how Iraq was able to pay Iraqi Government Officials and Personnel in the early days..

Edited by Stevarino
  • Upvote 1
Link to comment
Share on other sites

President isn't spending "Money"-- congress is. President only signs bills into law, he doesn't make them. He doesn't have an open account where he can just spend money either. Congress does. Your vote needs to focus on who is in congress. The President is a figure head. Yes, he has influence. But the decisions are made or lost in Congress.

  • Upvote 7
Link to comment
Share on other sites

President isn't spending "Money"-- congress is. President only signs bills into law, he doesn't make them. He doesn't have an open account where he can just spend money either. Congress does. Your vote needs to focus on who is in congress. The President is a figure head. Yes, he has influence. But the decisions are made or lost in Congress.

Of course BO is behind the insane spending. He pushed Congress to write and implement these crushing bills.

Actually, the Fed Reserve Bank of NY "owns" these Dinar! G W Bush signed a Presidential Order in 2004 enabling the Fed to buy, using US Dollars these Dinar from the GOI. This is how Iraq was able to pay Iraqi Government Officials and Personnel in the early days..

Thank you. That is very interesting. What that tells me is there is a huge incentive to help orchestrate an RV at as high a rate as can be justified because the US will be a huge beneficiary.

  • Upvote 4
  • Downvote 1
Link to comment
Share on other sites

Of course BO is behind the insane spending. He pushed Congress to write and implement these crushing bills.

Thank you. That is very interesting. What that tells me is there is a huge incentive to help orchestrate an RV at as high a rate as can be justified because the US will be a huge beneficiary.

Just part of the "Plan"..

  • Upvote 1
Link to comment
Share on other sites

Is it our money or Iraq's? What was behind wanting to earn interest for Iraq? Do you think "W" knew all the time there would be an RV because that was always the plan? Thx

Here is the plan that was written in 2003, so yes......GWB and others in our Govt. definitely had a plan previous to what we're seeing now, and many of the obstacles you now see are minimal compared to what was originally projected. Many of these obstacles are being worked right now, and some have already been worked out. Very interesting read, and done by a Post Naval Grad in May of 2003. Enjoy.

V

• Services

• Technology

http://www.nps.edu/Academics/centers/ccc/publications/OnlineJournal/2003/may03/middleEast.html Research

• Library

• Administration

• Academics

• About NPS

• NPS Home

Calendar | Directory SEARCH

A Monetary/Exchange Rate Strategy for the Reconstruction of Iraq

CCC > Research > Strategic Insights - An Online Journal > 2003

A Monetary/Exchange Rate Strategy for the Reconstruction of Iraq

Strategic Insights, Volume II, Issue 5 (May 2003)

by Robert Looney

Strategic Insights is a quarterly electronic journal produced by the Center for Contemporary Conflict at the Naval Postgraduate School in Monterey, California. The views expressed here are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily represent the views of NPS, the Department of Defense, or the U.S. Government.

Click here for a PDF version of this article.

Introduction

As the military conflict for Iraq concluded, a new battle began over the best way to rebuild the Iraqi economy. On the one side are those who believe that, by establishing proper institutions and rules, the Iraqis will be able to rebuild their own economy without an extended period of outside oversight and massive financial assistance. Another side sees the necessity of substantial infusions of foreign assistance and technical support over an extended period of time. A possible third group primarily led by the French and Russians feels that a new Iraqi government should set a high priority on paying back the tens of billions of dollars in loans taken by Saddam's government (Rahn 2003). While differing somewhat on ends and means, no doubt all sides would agree that any recovery of the Iraqi economy will entail successfully addressing a daunting set of tasks:

• Repairing a wrecked and neglected banking system that currently has at least three currencies in circulation: "Swiss" dinars," "Saadam" dinars, and now U.S. dollars.

• Beginning servicing and restructuring of the country's massive national debt.

• Resurrecting a whole spectrum of dilapidated industries.

• Revitalizing a declining and neglected agricultural sector.

• Propelling an economy based largely on cash, barter and international assistance into the 21st century.

• Reestablishing a consuming middle class that has all but disappeared.

• Diversifying an economy that currently depends upon a single commodity, oil.

• Replacing graft and corruption with a streamlined government that can collect taxes and enforce contracts.

• Commencing privatizing of inefficient public enterprises.

Although forging the country's economic recovery will be a daunting task, a number of lessons are apparent from the experiences of former-Soviet-block countries, as well as the reform programs of many of the formerly inward-oriented Latin American economies. Over the last several decades, more than a dozen countries, ranging from Chile to Poland, have gone through a transition from stagnant socialist to vibrant free-market democratic economies. Although each of these countries is unique in many regards, there are enough similarities to provide a rough understanding of what works and what doesn't. Uppermost is the establishment of the rule of law, an honest court system, and the protection of private property. Those formerly socialist countries that continued to have a corrupt and uncertain judicial system have had poor economic performance despite considerable economic reform. If private property rights are not protected, few will invest (Economist, "Rebuilding Iraq" April 17, 2003).

Another lesson learned from the transition economy experience is that progress will be difficult without the creation of a sound monetary system. Iraq has suffered very high rates of inflation in recent years but, given the oil wealth of the country, a sound currency could be quickly created. One obvious solution is to simply dollarize (or even euroize) the economy (Hanke, 2003). This could be done even before the creation of a new central bank. Specifically, simply let the dollar (or euro) circulate as the principal means of payment, with the money supply, as in the old gold standard, ultimately determined by the country's balance of payments position.

Several countries including Panama, Ecuador and El Salvador currently use the dollar as their official currency. Another alternative would be the creation of a new Iraqi dinar. Here a set of follow-on issues entail: (a) what rules should be used by an Iraqi Central Bank in issuing new dinars? and (B) how should the exchange rate be set with regard to other currencies? The sections below focus on these issues in an attempt to identify the best monetary system for facilitating Iraq's reconstruction, restructuring, and future economic growth.

Situation Immediately Following the End of the Conflict

The country's twenty-four million people are currently struggling to subsist in an economy based largely on cash, barter and international handouts. As Veith (April 12, 2003) notes "The nation is hobbled by high unemployment, poverty, spiraling inflation, and rampant corruption. Its middle class has all but disappeared. Taxes go uncollected, contracts unpaid. Agriculture has withered and other industries have collapsed. There are no official budgets or economic statistics. The government depends almost wholly on exports of a single commodity, petroleum, subject to sharp price swings."

Of particular concern is the country's external debt. While a precise figure is unavailable, the country's external financial obligations consist roughly of: $127 billion in debt, $57 billion in pending contracts (mostly with Russian companies), and $27 billion in compensation due to victims of the Iraqi invasion of Kuwait. Debts to Kuwait are estimated at around $17 billion, to other Gulf States $30 billion, and to Russia around $12 billion (Stelzer 1993).

Another problem area is the country's entire financial system. Baghdad's financial district is a mass of blown-out vaults, burned-out buildings, and broken glass. All nine floors of the Iraqi Central Bank have collapsed into a hollow shell.

Decades ago, Iraq's financial system was one of the region's most modern; its pool of well-educated technocrats helped other Middle Eastern countries, such as Jordan, establish their central banks. Unfortunately, the system was run into the ground by Saddam Hussein, who treated the Central Bank as his own private account. Under Hussein, the Bank lost its independent power to regulate exchange rates and interest rates.

Before the war, there were a few private banks, but the system was dominated by four state-run lenders. Baath Party loyalists received preferential loans from these banks. However, few Iraqis had bank deposits because of fear of seizure (Greimel, 2003). In short, a whole new financial system will have to be created as part of the early reconstruction effort.

Initial Steps towards Reconstruction

At the end of the war, work on these problems began across a wide set of fronts:

1. One of the key missions of the U.S. Treasury department's advance team in Iraq has been to gather basic information (Davis and Pope, 2003) about economic conditions in the country so that officials in Washington can make intelligent decisions about the best path to take towards alleviating bottlenecks and encouraging private participation. This fact-finding draws on Treasury expertise gained in assessing the prospects of many of the former Soviet economies at the time of their independence.

2. Immediate tasks include paying government salaries, determining the dinar's value, and establishing U.S. oversight of Iraq's central bank, Finance Ministry and other key agencies.

3. Concurrently, officials in Washington and perhaps the United Nations are expected to take initial steps to restore oil production, launch public works projects, mobilize donors, seek debt relief, stabilize the currency, cover balance-of-payments shortfalls, provide investment safeguards and help draft a government budget.

4. Although vague at this time (Duncan 2003), the international community is also expected to encourage the new government of Iraq to pursue ambitious longer-term reforms, such as modernizing commercial banking, reforming, the tax system, lowering tariffs and other trade restrictions, soliciting foreign investment, pursuing industrial diversification and privatizing government-run industries.

Currency Instability

An immediate concern has been the country's chaotic currency situation. After the Gulf War, Iraq replaced the old "Swiss" dinars (as they were known because they were printed in Switzerland) with "Saddam" dinars, and then printed ever larger quantities to make up for the government's chronic budget shortfalls. Though the government maintained the official exchange rate of Saddam dinars at 0.3 to the dollar, the black market exchange rate reached 2,000 to the dollar by the time Coalition Forces attacked Iraq. By the end of April 2003, their value is around 3,000 to the dollar.

Although not printed since 1990, the older, "Swiss" dinars continue to circulate in the autonomous Kurdish regions of northern Iraq. Most are ragged, sometimes held together with tape, and there is no central bank that controls their supply—they simply re-circulate in the regions (Andrews, 2003). Through March 2003 and into early April of this year, speculative buying had doubled the dollar value of these "Swiss" dinars.

U.S. Treasury officials are in the process of assessing the possibilities for printing new batches of the Swiss dinars in either Iraq or abroad. Although Iraq did have printing and engraving plants, officials say they do not yet know how many of them are still functional or whether they can produce bills with modern anti-counterfeiting features like holograms (Andrews, 2003).

Until a new system is established, the dollar will also be an "official" currency. The dollar has circulated widely in Iraq for years. By some estimates, Treasury officials say, as much as $500 million may have been circulating before the war. Small denomination dollars notes will be put into circulation through "emergency" payments to hundreds of thousands of Iraqi civil servants in an effort to quiet civic unrest and to stabilize the economy (Associated Press, 2003).

American officials are working with finance and postal ministry officials from Saddam Hussein's government to figure out appropriate wages. Under the Hussein regime, the central government tightly controlled wages and prices. Setting wages too high could worsen inflation that is already running at about 70% annually. At first, the Iraqi workers will be given $20 each in $1 and $5 bills. That is a large sum in Iraq, where a midlevel oil professional with a chemical degree used to make the equivalent of $50 a month.

Also with no central bank or functional commercial banking system, the U.S. Agency for International Development will begin offering loans of between $100 and $250,000 to individual entrepreneurs and to small to medium-sized businesses.

With no central bank or economic mechanisms to control the volume of dollars in circulation however, there is no assurance that inflation can be curbed, or resources allocated efficiently. Clearly, a top priority in reconstruction will have to be the establishment of a central bank that can oversee the country's monetary and financial system.

Possible Exchange Rate Regimes for Iraq

With the establishment of a central bank, the first issue at hand is whether it should immediately begin to issue its own currency. If it does, what are the policy options available? Which are superior? While a whole spectrum of flexible exchange rate systems are possible—managed flexible rates, gliding bands, adjustable pegs, etc.—given the dearth of financial and administrative expertise to properly manage a flexible rate system this option can be immediately ruled out as providing the stability needed over the next decade or so for reconstruction, though they are certainly realistic alternatives after the country has developed a sound financial system and is integrated into the global economy. Given this reality, the discussion below will be confined to the relative advantages and disadvantages of possible fixed rate systems.

Currency Union: If Iraq opted for this option, a foreign currency would act as legal tender. Monetary policy would simply be delegated to the anchor (country of currency origin); the currency that circulates domestically would be literally the same as that circulating in one of the major economies, probably the dollar or possibly the euro.

The motivation underlying this choice would be to get the maximum credibility for inflation-resistant monetary policy. Clearly maximum credibility derives from the fact that the country simply did not have a monetary policy because it lacked a currency to print. In technical terms it would largely eliminate the occurrence of a phenomenon that economists have dubbed the "time-inconsistency problem"—the fact that a government's incentive today to keep inflation low does not mean that a government will have the same incentive tomorrow. For example, one of the new political parties in Iraq may be elected on the promise that it will reduce inflation. After a few years in office, but before the next election, the party may begin to reconsider its original position. It will realize that it can probably gain additional political support if it increases the money supply to pay for extra social programs without directly taxing citizens. Moreover, inflation will not become apparent until after the elections.

The problem for the government is that over time people are not stupid. After the first bout of inflation, individuals will anticipate from the start the government's incentive to inflate before its term is over—the voters may never lower their inflation expectations. The problem is compounded when the government in power today may not be the government in power tomorrow. Consequently, any anti-inflation statements that a political party makes will not be believed. This is the essence of the time-inconsistency problem and why governments, in order to create a credible anti-inflation policy, may want to have an independent central bank that does not have the same incentives to inflate as do elected members of government. An independent central bank (or in this case the lack of a central bank) can make it more difficult if not impossible for current and future governments to change course on monetary policy.

Use of another country's currency would not be without its own set of problems. These fall in three main categories.

First, the optimal currency area literature suggests that real shocks (for example terms of trade shocks) are better accommodated through flexible exchange rates, and nominal shocks (for example money demand shocks) through fixed exchange rates. Iraq would no doubt experience greater external than internal shocks during most of the reconstruction process. Because the country has virtually no money markets, fluctuations in oil revenues would be buffeted by movements in the country's real exchange rate, if it had its own currency. Using the dollar, however, would force these adjustments on the domestic economy—less output, more unemployment.

Domestic economic contractions of this sort would be especially the case if Iraq's economy was not in the same phase of the business cycle as that of the country of currency origin. For example, a dramatic fall in oil prices would stimulate output and production in the United States perhaps to the point where monetary policy tightened to choke off excess demand. The subsequent increase in Iraqi interest rates would only accentuate the drop in aggregate demand in that country, thus compounding the severity of the oil price drop

Warner (2003) sums up this aspect of possible dollarization in Iraq:

The supply of dollars would be determined by the U.S., the interest rates would be determined by the U.S., and in effect Iraq's capacity to borrow would be determined by the U.S. It scarcely needs saying that what might be important to Iraq would not merit so much a mention at the monthly meetings of the Federal Reserve's Open Market Committee to determine monetary policy. The Cincinnati Cat Fish Company would get a better look than Iraq.

Second, there would be no seignorage revenues—the difference between the cost of printing money and the non-inflationary value of goods and services the authorities could purchase with the newly issued money. This can be a fairly sizeable amount. Studies have shown that this is likely to be at least twice the country's pre-dollarization monetary base (Schmitt-Grohe and Uribe, 2000), or in Iraq's case millions and millions of dollars over time. However, under the circumstance the authorities might be able to negotiate a seignorage sharing agreement with the United States whereby the U.S. compensated Iraq for its lost income.

Third, Iraq would lack the lender of last resort function—the ability of the central bank to discount commercial bank paper would be lost. In difficult times, commercial banks would not be able to build up their reserves by selling their assets at stable values to the central bank. Depending on its holdings of dollars/euros the fiscal authority (Ministry of Finance for example) might be able to perform the lender of last resort function, but this would not be assured. In short dollarization does not necessarily imply the loss of a lender of last resort, but simply the disappearance of one particular source of liquidity, namely central bank credit.

In sum, dollarization (or eurozation) would have the chief advantage of providing a stable monetary environment for the country to recover. The system would place few demands on the country's monetary authorities, allowing the central bank breathing space to upgrade its staff to the point (in a decade or so) where more sophisticated monetary management would be feasible. There would be costs, perhaps the highest being the political/psychological one of appearing to be a colony of the United States. This alone might rule out dollarization.

Currency Board: Under this system, Iraq would have its own "currency". But it would be constrained in managing that currency: (a) the dollar/"dinar" exchange rate would be fixed not just by policy, but by law; (B) a reserve requirement stipulating that each dollar/euro's worth of domestic currency is backed by a dollar/euro's worth of foreign reserves; and © a self-correcting balance of payments mechanism, in which a payments deficit automatically contracts the money supply, resulting in a contraction of spending. Like dollarization, a currency board can help to create a credible policy environment by removing from the monetary authorities the option of printing money to finance government deficits.

The first currency board was established by the British in Mauritius in 1849. The use of currency boards eventually spread to 70 British colonies. The purpose was to provide the colonies with a stable currency without the associated difficulty of issuing sterling notes and coins that were costly to replace if lost or destroyed. The colonies also benefited from this approach in that they could earn interest on the foreign currency assets being held in reserve. The use of currency boards peaked in the 1940s and declined thereafter. In the 1960s many newly independent African countries replaced their currency board with a central bank, and most other countries followed suit in the 1970s.

There is certainly precedent for this type of system in Iraq and in fact historically Iraq has used a system similar to that adopted by many of the former British colonies. When Iraq was part of the Ottoman Empire, a number of European currencies circulated alongside the Turkish pound. With the establishment of the British mandate after World War I, Iraq was incorporated into the Indian monetary system, which was operated by the British, and the rupee became the principal currency in circulation.

In 1931, the Iraq Currency Board was established in London for note issue and maintenance of reserves for the new Iraqi dinar. The currency board pursued a conservative monetary policy, maintaining very high reserves behind the dinar. The dinar was further strengthened by its link to the British pound. In 1947 the government-owned National Bank of Iraq was founded, and in 1949 the London-based currency board was abolished as the new bank assumed responsibility for the issuing of notes and the maintenance of reserves. The National Bank of Iraq continued the currency board's conservative monetary policy, maintaining 100 percent reserves behind outstanding domestic currency.

In more recent times, another Gulf country, the UAE, had considerable success with a currency board. This board was established in 1973 mainly for issuing the national currency, the Dirham, and defending its parity (which was set at 0.186621 grams of gold, and in terms of U.S. dollars it was 3.94737 Dirhams for one U.S. dollar, with a margin of fluctuation of plus or minus one percent).

Prior to the creation of the Currency Board, and from the time the Trucial States abandoned the Indian Gulf rupee in 1966, various regional currencies such as the Bahraini dinar and the Saiudi and Qatari/Dubai riyals had served as local currencies in one emirate or another. The board was given the authority not only to issue a common currency for the union, but also to exercise central banking functions over the commercial and banking sector (Khalifa, 1979, p. 63). As with the case of Iraq noted above the currency board was eventually fazed out for a more traditional central bank with the power to issue its own money, not necessarily backed up by foreign assets.

The introduction of currency board-like arrangements in Hong Kong (1983), Argentina (1991), Estonia (1992), Lithuania (1994), Bulgaria (1997), Bosnia (1998), Ecuador (2000) and El Salvador (2001) constitutes their resurgence in recent years. Clearly, however, the Argentine experience has forced a closer examination of the usefulness of this system. However, Hanke (2003) has noted that the main problem in Argentina was that the system was a "currency board-like" system and not a true currency board.

Currency boards are not a panacea, and while one could produce the stability required for Iraqi reconstruction it would unlikely succeed indefinitely without reforms to increase competitiveness. This was Argentina's downfall. Thus after an impressive start, the Argentine government failed to liberalize trade enough to sufficiently expand exports. They failed to change restrictive labor laws. They raised taxes above U.S. levels. The result was that Argentina was not enough of a contender to withstand external shocks, or count on future investor confidence (Schlaes, 2002).

The main advantage of the Currency Board over the Currency Union is largely that of political/national pride. However, on the assumption that over time the country's economic institutions develop and mature, the currency board might be a good transition to a more flexible exchange rate system more under control of the Iraqi authorities. Also on the plus side, the time inconsistency problem noted above would be reduced, but now subject to the perceived probability that the Board might be abandoned. As with the Currency Union, real exchange rate volatility would be diminished.

Monetary Union: A monetary union for Iraq would entail accepting a common currency issued by a common regional central bank. Presently, there are no current regional unions of this sort Iraq might join, although the GCC countries are in the process of forming a currency union—the completion date of which is tentatively set for 2010—too far in the future to be of assistance for the country's reconstruction. In any case, Iraq's membership in the GCC monetary union is quite problematical at this point. Iraq's population is considerably larger than that of any of the GCC countries, implying that that country might have considerable advantages in industrialization, thus being a threat to several existing GCC members, notably Saudi Arabia.

The benefits of a monetary union are similar to the first two systems examined above. It would also reduce the time inconsistency problem by requiring multinational agreement on policy. Real exchange rate volatility would also probably be reduced. For both, however, the result would be less certain than in the case of dollarization or a classic currency board. It would have all of the disadvantages associated with both systems.

Traditional Peg: This system would entail setting a fixed rate between the new Iraqi currency and either the dollar or the euro (or some index weighted by the two). The potential benefit is that the time inconsistency problem would be reduced through commitment to a verifiable target. The system is more flexible than the currency board in that a devaluation option would always be open, thus providing a potentially valuable policy tool in response to large shocks. The system would also reduce real exchange rate volatility. However, the ability to periodically change the exchange rate is also the system's most serious limitation, with the possibility of instability stemming from investor speculation over possible rate changes.

In addition, because the system would relax the fiscal constraint on the government expenditures (the dinar would no longer have a one-to-one backing of dollar/euro reserves), inflationary pressures might develop. In turn, these could lead to the so-called Dutch Disease effect (Looney, 1989), characterized by an overvalued foreign exchange rate limiting the ability of the country to develop broad based diversification into export markets. Through cheapening imports, the exchange rate would also limit import substitution industrialization for the large domestic market.

Finally, because of the increased uncertainty surrounding possible devaluations, the exchange rate would, from time-to-time become a target for speculative attacks, especially during periods of low reserves and or high external debt servicing commitments. In short the pegged rate would avoid real exchange rate volatility, but not necessarily persistent misalignments. The approach does not by itself place hard constraints on monetary and fiscal policy and thus provides only a partial solution against the time inconsistency problem. The credibility effects depend on accompanying institutional measures and the record of accomplishment. Here the authorities could gain considerable credence by introducing and successfully managing a oil revenue stabilization fund. Proper management of the fund would smooth out oil expenditures leading to reduced inflationary pressures and exchange rate issues: doubts about sustainability in the presence of full capital mobility.

Conclusions

The main considerations concerning possible monetary and exchange rate systems in Iraq are summarized in Figure 1. Considering the current disarray of the Iraqi economy, dollarization is likely to be the best system to initiate in the country. This system would provide stability while providing limited demands on the country's central bank and money managers.

No doubt, the political sensitivities of a new Iraqi government will soon dictate the initiation of a new Iraqi currency. Here, the currency board option appears to be the best currency/exchange rate alternative. The system would provide the country with price stability. It would also be consistent with the economy's gradual liberalization and integration into the world economy. Most importantly, such a system would also restore foreign confidence in the country's ability to provide a stable environment for investment. However, a currency board would probably not be optimal in the longer-term.

A country of Iraq's economic size will eventually grow to the point where a more flexible system would provide a better tool for macroeconomic management of the domestic economy. Still, the board would provide the Iraqi authorities with some breathing space until a new central bank had gathered the experience and expertise to introduce a more complex, flexible exchange rate system. At that point the country could move to a fixed exchange rate, linking the Iraqi dinar to the dollar/euro or some basket of the two.

To avoid an overvaluation of the dinar and possible Dutch Disease effects (Ebrahim-Zadeh, 2003), the country should simultaneously have a fiscal policy built around an oil stabilization fund (Barnett and Ossowski, 2003). In turn, the fund would be designed to smooth out as much as feasible fluctuations in oil revenues. Over time, successful management of the fund could contribute to the stability of the exchange rate and thus the country's completion of the reconstruction and restructuring of its economy.

For more insights into contemporary international security issues, see our Strategic Insights home page.

To have a new edition of Strategic Insights delivered to your inbox each quarter, please e-mail ccc@nps.edu with "Subscribe" in your subject line. Subscriptions are free, and your address will be used for no other purpose.

References

"Iraq's Currency Hodgepodge: Officials to Begin Payments Using U.S. Dollars, but Everything Else in Circulation will be Accepted," Associated Press, (April 16, 2003).

"Rebuilding Iraq" The Economist, April 17, 2003

"The Hard Path to New Nationhood," The Economist, April 17, 2003.

Andrews, Edmund L. "Iraq to Run of Dollars Till It Gets New Currency," New York Times, (April 18, 2003).

Barnett, Steven, and Rolando Ossowski, "What Goes Up…Why Oil Producing States Must Husband their Resources," Finance & Development, March 2003.

Davis, Bob, Chip Cummins and Simeon Kerr, "Dollars Are Sent to Iraq to Replace Dinars: Stopgap Move is Intended for Emergency Payments in Effort to Quiet Unrest," Wall Street Journal,, April 16, 2003

Davis, Bob and Hugh Pope "Numbers Crunch: Once an Economic Dynamo, Iraq is Now Financial Riddle—To Rebuild Nation, U.S. First Must Find Reliable Data," Wall Street Journal, April 9, 2003.

Duncan, Gary, "IMF Haze Obscures Iraq's Horizon," London Times, April 14, 2003

Ebrahim-zadej, Christine, "Dutch Disease: Too Much Wealth Managed Unwisely," Finance & Development, March 2003.

Greimel, Hans, "Iraq's Dire Banking Blues: With the Country's Entire Financial System in Tatters, a New Central Bank is Seen as a Top Priority," Ottawa Citizen, (April 22, 2003).

Hanke, Steve, "The Euro Could Help Iraq's Economic Recovery," Financial Times, April 16, 2003.

Jbili, Abdelali and Vitali Kramarenko, "Should MENA Countries Float or Peg?" Finance & Development, (March 2003).

Khalifa, Ali Mohammed, The United Arab Emirates: Unity in Fragmentation (Boulder Colorado: Westivew Press, 1970, p. 62.

Morris, Harvey, "Currency Stabilization a Priority for Iraq," Financial Times, April 8, 2002.

Looney, Robert E., "Oil Revenues and Viable Development: Impact of the Dutch Disease on Saudi Arabian Diversification Efforts," American-Arab Affairs (Winter 1988-89).

Schmitt-Grohe, Stephanie and Martin Uribe, Stabilization Policy and the Costs of Dollarization, Departmental Working Papers series, Rutgers University Dept of Economics (May 31, 2000)

Shlaes, Amity, "It is Dangerous to Elevate a Currency as a Political Emblem if the Need for Other Economic Reforms is Obscured," Jewish World Reviewm 2002.

Stelzer, Irwin M. "Forgive Them His Debts: How Much of Saddam's Financial Baggage Should the Iraqi People Have to Carry?" The Weekly Standard, April 21, 2003.

Vieth, Warren, "Teams Prepare to Jump-Start Iraq's Economy: The U.S. is Helping Lay the groundwork for a Wide Range of Monetary, Fiscal and Private Sector Reforms in the War-Ravaged Country," Los Angeles Times, April 12, 2003.

Warner, Jeremy, "Iraq's Dollarization," The Independent (London), April 18, 2003.

Contacts | Copyright/Accessibility | Privacy Policy | FOIA | Intranet Access

This is an official U.S. Navy website.

All information contained herein has been approved for release by the NPS Public Affairs Officer.

Page Last Updated: May 20, 2010 3:03:34 PM | Contact the Webmaster

  • Upvote 3
Link to comment
Share on other sites

I have heard several variations of this, but have never once have Iseen any article to validate or even give a little credibility to this, never mind even with a link.

I kind of liken this rumor to the one were Donald Trump bought a million Dollars worth.

Not saying it's not true, just over the last several years all I have ever seen was posters asking, and no one ever being able to confirm.

pp

Link to comment
Share on other sites

Here is the plan that was written in 2003, so yes......GWB and others in our Govt. definitely had a plan previous to what we're seeing now, and many of the obstacles you now see are minimal compared to what was originally projected. Many of these obstacles are being worked right now, and some have already been worked out. Very interesting read, and done by a Post Naval Grad in May of 2003. Enjoy.

V

• Services

• Technology

http://www.nps.edu/Academics/centers/ccc/publications/OnlineJournal/2003/may03/middleEast.html Research

• Library

• Administration

• Academics

• About NPS

• NPS Home

Calendar | Directory SEARCH

A Monetary/Exchange Rate Strategy for the Reconstruction of Iraq

CCC > Research > Strategic Insights - An Online Journal > 2003

A Monetary/Exchange Rate Strategy for the Reconstruction of Iraq

Strategic Insights, Volume II, Issue 5 (May 2003)

by Robert Looney

Strategic Insights is a quarterly electronic journal produced by the Center for Contemporary Conflict at the Naval Postgraduate School in Monterey, California. The views expressed here are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily represent the views of NPS, the Department of Defense, or the U.S. Government.

Click here for a PDF version of this article.

Introduction

As the military conflict for Iraq concluded, a new battle began over the best way to rebuild the Iraqi economy. On the one side are those who believe that, by establishing proper institutions and rules, the Iraqis will be able to rebuild their own economy without an extended period of outside oversight and massive financial assistance. Another side sees the necessity of substantial infusions of foreign assistance and technical support over an extended period of time. A possible third group primarily led by the French and Russians feels that a new Iraqi government should set a high priority on paying back the tens of billions of dollars in loans taken by Saddam's government (Rahn 2003). While differing somewhat on ends and means, no doubt all sides would agree that any recovery of the Iraqi economy will entail successfully addressing a daunting set of tasks:

• Repairing a wrecked and neglected banking system that currently has at least three currencies in circulation: "Swiss" dinars," "Saadam" dinars, and now U.S. dollars.

• Beginning servicing and restructuring of the country's massive national debt.

• Resurrecting a whole spectrum of dilapidated industries.

• Revitalizing a declining and neglected agricultural sector.

• Propelling an economy based largely on cash, barter and international assistance into the 21st century.

• Reestablishing a consuming middle class that has all but disappeared.

• Diversifying an economy that currently depends upon a single commodity, oil.

• Replacing graft and corruption with a streamlined government that can collect taxes and enforce contracts.

• Commencing privatizing of inefficient public enterprises.

Although forging the country's economic recovery will be a daunting task, a number of lessons are apparent from the experiences of former-Soviet-block countries, as well as the reform programs of many of the formerly inward-oriented Latin American economies. Over the last several decades, more than a dozen countries, ranging from Chile to Poland, have gone through a transition from stagnant socialist to vibrant free-market democratic economies. Although each of these countries is unique in many regards, there are enough similarities to provide a rough understanding of what works and what doesn't. Uppermost is the establishment of the rule of law, an honest court system, and the protection of private property. Those formerly socialist countries that continued to have a corrupt and uncertain judicial system have had poor economic performance despite considerable economic reform. If private property rights are not protected, few will invest (Economist, "Rebuilding Iraq" April 17, 2003).

Another lesson learned from the transition economy experience is that progress will be difficult without the creation of a sound monetary system. Iraq has suffered very high rates of inflation in recent years but, given the oil wealth of the country, a sound currency could be quickly created. One obvious solution is to simply dollarize (or even euroize) the economy (Hanke, 2003). This could be done even before the creation of a new central bank. Specifically, simply let the dollar (or euro) circulate as the principal means of payment, with the money supply, as in the old gold standard, ultimately determined by the country's balance of payments position.

Several countries including Panama, Ecuador and El Salvador currently use the dollar as their official currency. Another alternative would be the creation of a new Iraqi dinar. Here a set of follow-on issues entail: (a) what rules should be used by an Iraqi Central Bank in issuing new dinars? and (B) how should the exchange rate be set with regard to other currencies? The sections below focus on these issues in an attempt to identify the best monetary system for facilitating Iraq's reconstruction, restructuring, and future economic growth.

Situation Immediately Following the End of the Conflict

The country's twenty-four million people are currently struggling to subsist in an economy based largely on cash, barter and international handouts. As Veith (April 12, 2003) notes "The nation is hobbled by high unemployment, poverty, spiraling inflation, and rampant corruption. Its middle class has all but disappeared. Taxes go uncollected, contracts unpaid. Agriculture has withered and other industries have collapsed. There are no official budgets or economic statistics. The government depends almost wholly on exports of a single commodity, petroleum, subject to sharp price swings."

Of particular concern is the country's external debt. While a precise figure is unavailable, the country's external financial obligations consist roughly of: $127 billion in debt, $57 billion in pending contracts (mostly with Russian companies), and $27 billion in compensation due to victims of the Iraqi invasion of Kuwait. Debts to Kuwait are estimated at around $17 billion, to other Gulf States $30 billion, and to Russia around $12 billion (Stelzer 1993).

Another problem area is the country's entire financial system. Baghdad's financial district is a mass of blown-out vaults, burned-out buildings, and broken glass. All nine floors of the Iraqi Central Bank have collapsed into a hollow shell.

Decades ago, Iraq's financial system was one of the region's most modern; its pool of well-educated technocrats helped other Middle Eastern countries, such as Jordan, establish their central banks. Unfortunately, the system was run into the ground by Saddam Hussein, who treated the Central Bank as his own private account. Under Hussein, the Bank lost its independent power to regulate exchange rates and interest rates.

Before the war, there were a few private banks, but the system was dominated by four state-run lenders. Baath Party loyalists received preferential loans from these banks. However, few Iraqis had bank deposits because of fear of seizure (Greimel, 2003). In short, a whole new financial system will have to be created as part of the early reconstruction effort.

Initial Steps towards Reconstruction

At the end of the war, work on these problems began across a wide set of fronts:

1. One of the key missions of the U.S. Treasury department's advance team in Iraq has been to gather basic information (Davis and Pope, 2003) about economic conditions in the country so that officials in Washington can make intelligent decisions about the best path to take towards alleviating bottlenecks and encouraging private participation. This fact-finding draws on Treasury expertise gained in assessing the prospects of many of the former Soviet economies at the time of their independence.

2. Immediate tasks include paying government salaries, determining the dinar's value, and establishing U.S. oversight of Iraq's central bank, Finance Ministry and other key agencies.

3. Concurrently, officials in Washington and perhaps the United Nations are expected to take initial steps to restore oil production, launch public works projects, mobilize donors, seek debt relief, stabilize the currency, cover balance-of-payments shortfalls, provide investment safeguards and help draft a government budget.

4. Although vague at this time (Duncan 2003), the international community is also expected to encourage the new government of Iraq to pursue ambitious longer-term reforms, such as modernizing commercial banking, reforming, the tax system, lowering tariffs and other trade restrictions, soliciting foreign investment, pursuing industrial diversification and privatizing government-run industries.

Currency Instability

An immediate concern has been the country's chaotic currency situation. After the Gulf War, Iraq replaced the old "Swiss" dinars (as they were known because they were printed in Switzerland) with "Saddam" dinars, and then printed ever larger quantities to make up for the government's chronic budget shortfalls. Though the government maintained the official exchange rate of Saddam dinars at 0.3 to the dollar, the black market exchange rate reached 2,000 to the dollar by the time Coalition Forces attacked Iraq. By the end of April 2003, their value is around 3,000 to the dollar.

Although not printed since 1990, the older, "Swiss" dinars continue to circulate in the autonomous Kurdish regions of northern Iraq. Most are ragged, sometimes held together with tape, and there is no central bank that controls their supply—they simply re-circulate in the regions (Andrews, 2003). Through March 2003 and into early April of this year, speculative buying had doubled the dollar value of these "Swiss" dinars.

U.S. Treasury officials are in the process of assessing the possibilities for printing new batches of the Swiss dinars in either Iraq or abroad. Although Iraq did have printing and engraving plants, officials say they do not yet know how many of them are still functional or whether they can produce bills with modern anti-counterfeiting features like holograms (Andrews, 2003).

Until a new system is established, the dollar will also be an "official" currency. The dollar has circulated widely in Iraq for years. By some estimates, Treasury officials say, as much as $500 million may have been circulating before the war. Small denomination dollars notes will be put into circulation through "emergency" payments to hundreds of thousands of Iraqi civil servants in an effort to quiet civic unrest and to stabilize the economy (Associated Press, 2003).

American officials are working with finance and postal ministry officials from Saddam Hussein's government to figure out appropriate wages. Under the Hussein regime, the central government tightly controlled wages and prices. Setting wages too high could worsen inflation that is already running at about 70% annually. At first, the Iraqi workers will be given $20 each in $1 and $5 bills. That is a large sum in Iraq, where a midlevel oil professional with a chemical degree used to make the equivalent of $50 a month.

Also with no central bank or functional commercial banking system, the U.S. Agency for International Development will begin offering loans of between $100 and $250,000 to individual entrepreneurs and to small to medium-sized businesses.

With no central bank or economic mechanisms to control the volume of dollars in circulation however, there is no assurance that inflation can be curbed, or resources allocated efficiently. Clearly, a top priority in reconstruction will have to be the establishment of a central bank that can oversee the country's monetary and financial system.

Possible Exchange Rate Regimes for Iraq

With the establishment of a central bank, the first issue at hand is whether it should immediately begin to issue its own currency. If it does, what are the policy options available? Which are superior? While a whole spectrum of flexible exchange rate systems are possible—managed flexible rates, gliding bands, adjustable pegs, etc.—given the dearth of financial and administrative expertise to properly manage a flexible rate system this option can be immediately ruled out as providing the stability needed over the next decade or so for reconstruction, though they are certainly realistic alternatives after the country has developed a sound financial system and is integrated into the global economy. Given this reality, the discussion below will be confined to the relative advantages and disadvantages of possible fixed rate systems.

Currency Union: If Iraq opted for this option, a foreign currency would act as legal tender. Monetary policy would simply be delegated to the anchor (country of currency origin); the currency that circulates domestically would be literally the same as that circulating in one of the major economies, probably the dollar or possibly the euro.

The motivation underlying this choice would be to get the maximum credibility for inflation-resistant monetary policy. Clearly maximum credibility derives from the fact that the country simply did not have a monetary policy because it lacked a currency to print. In technical terms it would largely eliminate the occurrence of a phenomenon that economists have dubbed the "time-inconsistency problem"—the fact that a government's incentive today to keep inflation low does not mean that a government will have the same incentive tomorrow. For example, one of the new political parties in Iraq may be elected on the promise that it will reduce inflation. After a few years in office, but before the next election, the party may begin to reconsider its original position. It will realize that it can probably gain additional political support if it increases the money supply to pay for extra social programs without directly taxing citizens. Moreover, inflation will not become apparent until after the elections.

The problem for the government is that over time people are not stupid. After the first bout of inflation, individuals will anticipate from the start the government's incentive to inflate before its term is over—the voters may never lower their inflation expectations. The problem is compounded when the government in power today may not be the government in power tomorrow. Consequently, any anti-inflation statements that a political party makes will not be believed. This is the essence of the time-inconsistency problem and why governments, in order to create a credible anti-inflation policy, may want to have an independent central bank that does not have the same incentives to inflate as do elected members of government. An independent central bank (or in this case the lack of a central bank) can make it more difficult if not impossible for current and future governments to change course on monetary policy.

Use of another country's currency would not be without its own set of problems. These fall in three main categories.

First, the optimal currency area literature suggests that real shocks (for example terms of trade shocks) are better accommodated through flexible exchange rates, and nominal shocks (for example money demand shocks) through fixed exchange rates. Iraq would no doubt experience greater external than internal shocks during most of the reconstruction process. Because the country has virtually no money markets, fluctuations in oil revenues would be buffeted by movements in the country's real exchange rate, if it had its own currency. Using the dollar, however, would force these adjustments on the domestic economy—less output, more unemployment.

Domestic economic contractions of this sort would be especially the case if Iraq's economy was not in the same phase of the business cycle as that of the country of currency origin. For example, a dramatic fall in oil prices would stimulate output and production in the United States perhaps to the point where monetary policy tightened to choke off excess demand. The subsequent increase in Iraqi interest rates would only accentuate the drop in aggregate demand in that country, thus compounding the severity of the oil price drop

Warner (2003) sums up this aspect of possible dollarization in Iraq:

The supply of dollars would be determined by the U.S., the interest rates would be determined by the U.S., and in effect Iraq's capacity to borrow would be determined by the U.S. It scarcely needs saying that what might be important to Iraq would not merit so much a mention at the monthly meetings of the Federal Reserve's Open Market Committee to determine monetary policy. The Cincinnati Cat Fish Company would get a better look than Iraq.

Second, there would be no seignorage revenues—the difference between the cost of printing money and the non-inflationary value of goods and services the authorities could purchase with the newly issued money. This can be a fairly sizeable amount. Studies have shown that this is likely to be at least twice the country's pre-dollarization monetary base (Schmitt-Grohe and Uribe, 2000), or in Iraq's case millions and millions of dollars over time. However, under the circumstance the authorities might be able to negotiate a seignorage sharing agreement with the United States whereby the U.S. compensated Iraq for its lost income.

Third, Iraq would lack the lender of last resort function—the ability of the central bank to discount commercial bank paper would be lost. In difficult times, commercial banks would not be able to build up their reserves by selling their assets at stable values to the central bank. Depending on its holdings of dollars/euros the fiscal authority (Ministry of Finance for example) might be able to perform the lender of last resort function, but this would not be assured. In short dollarization does not necessarily imply the loss of a lender of last resort, but simply the disappearance of one particular source of liquidity, namely central bank credit.

In sum, dollarization (or eurozation) would have the chief advantage of providing a stable monetary environment for the country to recover. The system would place few demands on the country's monetary authorities, allowing the central bank breathing space to upgrade its staff to the point (in a decade or so) where more sophisticated monetary management would be feasible. There would be costs, perhaps the highest being the political/psychological one of appearing to be a colony of the United States. This alone might rule out dollarization.

Currency Board: Under this system, Iraq would have its own "currency". But it would be constrained in managing that currency: (a) the dollar/"dinar" exchange rate would be fixed not just by policy, but by law; (B) a reserve requirement stipulating that each dollar/euro's worth of domestic currency is backed by a dollar/euro's worth of foreign reserves; and © a self-correcting balance of payments mechanism, in which a payments deficit automatically contracts the money supply, resulting in a contraction of spending. Like dollarization, a currency board can help to create a credible policy environment by removing from the monetary authorities the option of printing money to finance government deficits.

The first currency board was established by the British in Mauritius in 1849. The use of currency boards eventually spread to 70 British colonies. The purpose was to provide the colonies with a stable currency without the associated difficulty of issuing sterling notes and coins that were costly to replace if lost or destroyed. The colonies also benefited from this approach in that they could earn interest on the foreign currency assets being held in reserve. The use of currency boards peaked in the 1940s and declined thereafter. In the 1960s many newly independent African countries replaced their currency board with a central bank, and most other countries followed suit in the 1970s.

There is certainly precedent for this type of system in Iraq and in fact historically Iraq has used a system similar to that adopted by many of the former British colonies. When Iraq was part of the Ottoman Empire, a number of European currencies circulated alongside the Turkish pound. With the establishment of the British mandate after World War I, Iraq was incorporated into the Indian monetary system, which was operated by the British, and the rupee became the principal currency in circulation.

In 1931, the Iraq Currency Board was established in London for note issue and maintenance of reserves for the new Iraqi dinar. The currency board pursued a conservative monetary policy, maintaining very high reserves behind the dinar. The dinar was further strengthened by its link to the British pound. In 1947 the government-owned National Bank of Iraq was founded, and in 1949 the London-based currency board was abolished as the new bank assumed responsibility for the issuing of notes and the maintenance of reserves. The National Bank of Iraq continued the currency board's conservative monetary policy, maintaining 100 percent reserves behind outstanding domestic currency.

In more recent times, another Gulf country, the UAE, had considerable success with a currency board. This board was established in 1973 mainly for issuing the national currency, the Dirham, and defending its parity (which was set at 0.186621 grams of gold, and in terms of U.S. dollars it was 3.94737 Dirhams for one U.S. dollar, with a margin of fluctuation of plus or minus one percent).

Prior to the creation of the Currency Board, and from the time the Trucial States abandoned the Indian Gulf rupee in 1966, various regional currencies such as the Bahraini dinar and the Saiudi and Qatari/Dubai riyals had served as local currencies in one emirate or another. The board was given the authority not only to issue a common currency for the union, but also to exercise central banking functions over the commercial and banking sector (Khalifa, 1979, p. 63). As with the case of Iraq noted above the currency board was eventually fazed out for a more traditional central bank with the power to issue its own money, not necessarily backed up by foreign assets.

The introduction of currency board-like arrangements in Hong Kong (1983), Argentina (1991), Estonia (1992), Lithuania (1994), Bulgaria (1997), Bosnia (1998), Ecuador (2000) and El Salvador (2001) constitutes their resurgence in recent years. Clearly, however, the Argentine experience has forced a closer examination of the usefulness of this system. However, Hanke (2003) has noted that the main problem in Argentina was that the system was a "currency board-like" system and not a true currency board.

Currency boards are not a panacea, and while one could produce the stability required for Iraqi reconstruction it would unlikely succeed indefinitely without reforms to increase competitiveness. This was Argentina's downfall. Thus after an impressive start, the Argentine government failed to liberalize trade enough to sufficiently expand exports. They failed to change restrictive labor laws. They raised taxes above U.S. levels. The result was that Argentina was not enough of a contender to withstand external shocks, or count on future investor confidence (Schlaes, 2002).

The main advantage of the Currency Board over the Currency Union is largely that of political/national pride. However, on the assumption that over time the country's economic institutions develop and mature, the currency board might be a good transition to a more flexible exchange rate system more under control of the Iraqi authorities. Also on the plus side, the time inconsistency problem noted above would be reduced, but now subject to the perceived probability that the Board might be abandoned. As with the Currency Union, real exchange rate volatility would be diminished.

Monetary Union: A monetary union for Iraq would entail accepting a common currency issued by a common regional central bank. Presently, there are no current regional unions of this sort Iraq might join, although the GCC countries are in the process of forming a currency union—the completion date of which is tentatively set for 2010—too far in the future to be of assistance for the country's reconstruction. In any case, Iraq's membership in the GCC monetary union is quite problematical at this point. Iraq's population is considerably larger than that of any of the GCC countries, implying that that country might have considerable advantages in industrialization, thus being a threat to several existing GCC members, notably Saudi Arabia.

The benefits of a monetary union are similar to the first two systems examined above. It would also reduce the time inconsistency problem by requiring multinational agreement on policy. Real exchange rate volatility would also probably be reduced. For both, however, the result would be less certain than in the case of dollarization or a classic currency board. It would have all of the disadvantages associated with both systems.

Traditional Peg: This system would entail setting a fixed rate between the new Iraqi currency and either the dollar or the euro (or some index weighted by the two). The potential benefit is that the time inconsistency problem would be reduced through commitment to a verifiable target. The system is more flexible than the currency board in that a devaluation option would always be open, thus providing a potentially valuable policy tool in response to large shocks. The system would also reduce real exchange rate volatility. However, the ability to periodically change the exchange rate is also the system's most serious limitation, with the possibility of instability stemming from investor speculation over possible rate changes.

In addition, because the system would relax the fiscal constraint on the government expenditures (the dinar would no longer have a one-to-one backing of dollar/euro reserves), inflationary pressures might develop. In turn, these could lead to the so-called Dutch Disease effect (Looney, 1989), characterized by an overvalued foreign exchange rate limiting the ability of the country to develop broad based diversification into export markets. Through cheapening imports, the exchange rate would also limit import substitution industrialization for the large domestic market.

Finally, because of the increased uncertainty surrounding possible devaluations, the exchange rate would, from time-to-time become a target for speculative attacks, especially during periods of low reserves and or high external debt servicing commitments. In short the pegged rate would avoid real exchange rate volatility, but not necessarily persistent misalignments. The approach does not by itself place hard constraints on monetary and fiscal policy and thus provides only a partial solution against the time inconsistency problem. The credibility effects depend on accompanying institutional measures and the record of accomplishment. Here the authorities could gain considerable credence by introducing and successfully managing a oil revenue stabilization fund. Proper management of the fund would smooth out oil expenditures leading to reduced inflationary pressures and exchange rate issues: doubts about sustainability in the presence of full capital mobility.

Conclusions

The main considerations concerning possible monetary and exchange rate systems in Iraq are summarized in Figure 1. Considering the current disarray of the Iraqi economy, dollarization is likely to be the best system to initiate in the country. This system would provide stability while providing limited demands on the country's central bank and money managers.

No doubt, the political sensitivities of a new Iraqi government will soon dictate the initiation of a new Iraqi currency. Here, the currency board option appears to be the best currency/exchange rate alternative. The system would provide the country with price stability. It would also be consistent with the economy's gradual liberalization and integration into the world economy. Most importantly, such a system would also restore foreign confidence in the country's ability to provide a stable environment for investment. However, a currency board would probably not be optimal in the longer-term.

A country of Iraq's economic size will eventually grow to the point where a more flexible system would provide a better tool for macroeconomic management of the domestic economy. Still, the board would provide the Iraqi authorities with some breathing space until a new central bank had gathered the experience and expertise to introduce a more complex, flexible exchange rate system. At that point the country could move to a fixed exchange rate, linking the Iraqi dinar to the dollar/euro or some basket of the two.

To avoid an overvaluation of the dinar and possible Dutch Disease effects (Ebrahim-Zadeh, 2003), the country should simultaneously have a fiscal policy built around an oil stabilization fund (Barnett and Ossowski, 2003). In turn, the fund would be designed to smooth out as much as feasible fluctuations in oil revenues. Over time, successful management of the fund could contribute to the stability of the exchange rate and thus the country's completion of the reconstruction and restructuring of its economy.

For more insights into contemporary international security issues, see our Strategic Insights home page.

To have a new edition of Strategic Insights delivered to your inbox each quarter, please e-mail ccc@nps.edu with "Subscribe" in your subject line. Subscriptions are free, and your address will be used for no other purpose.

References

"Iraq's Currency Hodgepodge: Officials to Begin Payments Using U.S. Dollars, but Everything Else in Circulation will be Accepted," Associated Press, (April 16, 2003).

"Rebuilding Iraq" The Economist, April 17, 2003

"The Hard Path to New Nationhood," The Economist, April 17, 2003.

Andrews, Edmund L. "Iraq to Run of Dollars Till It Gets New Currency," New York Times, (April 18, 2003).

Barnett, Steven, and Rolando Ossowski, "What Goes Up…Why Oil Producing States Must Husband their Resources," Finance & Development, March 2003.

Davis, Bob, Chip Cummins and Simeon Kerr, "Dollars Are Sent to Iraq to Replace Dinars: Stopgap Move is Intended for Emergency Payments in Effort to Quiet Unrest," Wall Street Journal,, April 16, 2003

Davis, Bob and Hugh Pope "Numbers Crunch: Once an Economic Dynamo, Iraq is Now Financial Riddle—To Rebuild Nation, U.S. First Must Find Reliable Data," Wall Street Journal, April 9, 2003.

Duncan, Gary, "IMF Haze Obscures Iraq's Horizon," London Times, April 14, 2003

Ebrahim-zadej, Christine, "Dutch Disease: Too Much Wealth Managed Unwisely," Finance & Development, March 2003.

Greimel, Hans, "Iraq's Dire Banking Blues: With the Country's Entire Financial System in Tatters, a New Central Bank is Seen as a Top Priority," Ottawa Citizen, (April 22, 2003).

Hanke, Steve, "The Euro Could Help Iraq's Economic Recovery," Financial Times, April 16, 2003.

Jbili, Abdelali and Vitali Kramarenko, "Should MENA Countries Float or Peg?" Finance & Development, (March 2003).

Khalifa, Ali Mohammed, The United Arab Emirates: Unity in Fragmentation (Boulder Colorado: Westivew Press, 1970, p. 62.

Morris, Harvey, "Currency Stabilization a Priority for Iraq," Financial Times, April 8, 2002.

Looney, Robert E., "Oil Revenues and Viable Development: Impact of the Dutch Disease on Saudi Arabian Diversification Efforts," American-Arab Affairs (Winter 1988-89).

Schmitt-Grohe, Stephanie and Martin Uribe, Stabilization Policy and the Costs of Dollarization, Departmental Working Papers series, Rutgers University Dept of Economics (May 31, 2000)

Shlaes, Amity, "It is Dangerous to Elevate a Currency as a Political Emblem if the Need for Other Economic Reforms is Obscured," Jewish World Reviewm 2002.

Stelzer, Irwin M. "Forgive Them His Debts: How Much of Saddam's Financial Baggage Should the Iraqi People Have to Carry?" The Weekly Standard, April 21, 2003.

Vieth, Warren, "Teams Prepare to Jump-Start Iraq's Economy: The U.S. is Helping Lay the groundwork for a Wide Range of Monetary, Fiscal and Private Sector Reforms in the War-Ravaged Country," Los Angeles Times, April 12, 2003.

Warner, Jeremy, "Iraq's Dollarization," The Independent (London), April 18, 2003.

Contacts | Copyright/Accessibility | Privacy Policy | FOIA | Intranet Access

This is an official U.S. Navy website.

All information contained herein has been approved for release by the NPS Public Affairs Officer.

Page Last Updated: May 20, 2010 3:03:34 PM | Contact the Webmaster

Let's get on with restoring the confidence in Iraq's currency and GO RV......now!

  • Upvote 1
  • Downvote 4
Link to comment
Share on other sites

To me, the amount of IQD currently in circulation is one of the two key pieces that is missing in all of this. I have heard many figures but haven't seen anything official. I'm not sure if Scooter has found this information in his research or not but I believe he has been looking for it.

A week or two ago someone said the total amount of all money in circulation throughout the world is $60 Trillion USD. I don't know if this is true or not but if true it provides a guide for us about what's realistic with the RV and what is not.

I mentioned in several other threads that a few weeks ago the G-20 press release for the meeting that will be held this weekend said that they were:

"committed to implement the unprecedented and most coordinated expansionary macroeconomic policies, including the fiscal expansion of US$5 trillion and the unconventional monetary policy instruments"

To me, that tells us the amount the RV could be valued at when added to the amount that the IQD is currently now worth. That $5 trillion has to come from somewhere. The other countries aren't going to print that much money so where else would this fiscal expansion come from?

IF that's the case then the amount in circulation is key to determining the rate.

The other important factor to me is what type of deal does the US, China and Europe have in place with regard to the IQD they are holding. Will the $5 Trillion added in the fiscal expansion be applied to the amount that they will have in their reserves so the money is added to prop up the economy but it isn't put into actual circulation?

I have a lot of questions but not many answers about this. Hopefully Scooter or some other knowledgeable person can answer them.

Link to comment
Share on other sites

Here is the plan that was written in 2003, so yes......GWB and others in our Govt. definitely had a plan previous to what we're seeing now, and many of the obstacles you now see are minimal compared to what was originally projected. Many of these obstacles are being worked right now, and some have already been worked out. Very interesting read, and done by a Post Naval Grad in May of 2003. Enjoy.

V

• Services

• Technology

http://www.nps.edu/Academics/centers/ccc/publications/OnlineJournal/2003/may03/middleEast.html Research

• Library

• Administration

• Academics

• About NPS

• NPS Home

Calendar | Directory SEARCH

A Monetary/Exchange Rate Strategy for the Reconstruction of Iraq

CCC > Research > Strategic Insights - An Online Journal > 2003

A Monetary/Exchange Rate Strategy for the Reconstruction of Iraq

Strategic Insights, Volume II, Issue 5 (May 2003)

by Robert Looney

Strategic Insights is a quarterly electronic journal produced by the Center for Contemporary Conflict at the Naval Postgraduate School in Monterey, California. The views expressed here are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily represent the views of NPS, the Department of Defense, or the U.S. Government.

Click here for a PDF version of this article.

Introduction

As the military conflict for Iraq concluded, a new battle began over the best way to rebuild the Iraqi economy. On the one side are those who believe that, by establishing proper institutions and rules, the Iraqis will be able to rebuild their own economy without an extended period of outside oversight and massive financial assistance. Another side sees the necessity of substantial infusions of foreign assistance and technical support over an extended period of time. A possible third group primarily led by the French and Russians feels that a new Iraqi government should set a high priority on paying back the tens of billions of dollars in loans taken by Saddam's government (Rahn 2003). While differing somewhat on ends and means, no doubt all sides would agree that any recovery of the Iraqi economy will entail successfully addressing a daunting set of tasks:

• Repairing a wrecked and neglected banking system that currently has at least three currencies in circulation: "Swiss" dinars," "Saadam" dinars, and now U.S. dollars.

• Beginning servicing and restructuring of the country's massive national debt.

• Resurrecting a whole spectrum of dilapidated industries.

• Revitalizing a declining and neglected agricultural sector.

• Propelling an economy based largely on cash, barter and international assistance into the 21st century.

• Reestablishing a consuming middle class that has all but disappeared.

• Diversifying an economy that currently depends upon a single commodity, oil.

• Replacing graft and corruption with a streamlined government that can collect taxes and enforce contracts.

• Commencing privatizing of inefficient public enterprises.

Although forging the country's economic recovery will be a daunting task, a number of lessons are apparent from the experiences of former-Soviet-block countries, as well as the reform programs of many of the formerly inward-oriented Latin American economies. Over the last several decades, more than a dozen countries, ranging from Chile to Poland, have gone through a transition from stagnant socialist to vibrant free-market democratic economies. Although each of these countries is unique in many regards, there are enough similarities to provide a rough understanding of what works and what doesn't. Uppermost is the establishment of the rule of law, an honest court system, and the protection of private property. Those formerly socialist countries that continued to have a corrupt and uncertain judicial system have had poor economic performance despite considerable economic reform. If private property rights are not protected, few will invest (Economist, "Rebuilding Iraq" April 17, 2003).

Another lesson learned from the transition economy experience is that progress will be difficult without the creation of a sound monetary system. Iraq has suffered very high rates of inflation in recent years but, given the oil wealth of the country, a sound currency could be quickly created. One obvious solution is to simply dollarize (or even euroize) the economy (Hanke, 2003). This could be done even before the creation of a new central bank. Specifically, simply let the dollar (or euro) circulate as the principal means of payment, with the money supply, as in the old gold standard, ultimately determined by the country's balance of payments position.

Several countries including Panama, Ecuador and El Salvador currently use the dollar as their official currency. Another alternative would be the creation of a new Iraqi dinar. Here a set of follow-on issues entail: (a) what rules should be used by an Iraqi Central Bank in issuing new dinars? and (B) how should the exchange rate be set with regard to other currencies? The sections below focus on these issues in an attempt to identify the best monetary system for facilitating Iraq's reconstruction, restructuring, and future economic growth.

Situation Immediately Following the End of the Conflict

The country's twenty-four million people are currently struggling to subsist in an economy based largely on cash, barter and international handouts. As Veith (April 12, 2003) notes "The nation is hobbled by high unemployment, poverty, spiraling inflation, and rampant corruption. Its middle class has all but disappeared. Taxes go uncollected, contracts unpaid. Agriculture has withered and other industries have collapsed. There are no official budgets or economic statistics. The government depends almost wholly on exports of a single commodity, petroleum, subject to sharp price swings."

Of particular concern is the country's external debt. While a precise figure is unavailable, the country's external financial obligations consist roughly of: $127 billion in debt, $57 billion in pending contracts (mostly with Russian companies), and $27 billion in compensation due to victims of the Iraqi invasion of Kuwait. Debts to Kuwait are estimated at around $17 billion, to other Gulf States $30 billion, and to Russia around $12 billion (Stelzer 1993).

Another problem area is the country's entire financial system. Baghdad's financial district is a mass of blown-out vaults, burned-out buildings, and broken glass. All nine floors of the Iraqi Central Bank have collapsed into a hollow shell.

Decades ago, Iraq's financial system was one of the region's most modern; its pool of well-educated technocrats helped other Middle Eastern countries, such as Jordan, establish their central banks. Unfortunately, the system was run into the ground by Saddam Hussein, who treated the Central Bank as his own private account. Under Hussein, the Bank lost its independent power to regulate exchange rates and interest rates.

Before the war, there were a few private banks, but the system was dominated by four state-run lenders. Baath Party loyalists received preferential loans from these banks. However, few Iraqis had bank deposits because of fear of seizure (Greimel, 2003). In short, a whole new financial system will have to be created as part of the early reconstruction effort.

Initial Steps towards Reconstruction

At the end of the war, work on these problems began across a wide set of fronts:

1. One of the key missions of the U.S. Treasury department's advance team in Iraq has been to gather basic information (Davis and Pope, 2003) about economic conditions in the country so that officials in Washington can make intelligent decisions about the best path to take towards alleviating bottlenecks and encouraging private participation. This fact-finding draws on Treasury expertise gained in assessing the prospects of many of the former Soviet economies at the time of their independence.

2. Immediate tasks include paying government salaries, determining the dinar's value, and establishing U.S. oversight of Iraq's central bank, Finance Ministry and other key agencies.

3. Concurrently, officials in Washington and perhaps the United Nations are expected to take initial steps to restore oil production, launch public works projects, mobilize donors, seek debt relief, stabilize the currency, cover balance-of-payments shortfalls, provide investment safeguards and help draft a government budget.

4. Although vague at this time (Duncan 2003), the international community is also expected to encourage the new government of Iraq to pursue ambitious longer-term reforms, such as modernizing commercial banking, reforming, the tax system, lowering tariffs and other trade restrictions, soliciting foreign investment, pursuing industrial diversification and privatizing government-run industries.

Currency Instability

An immediate concern has been the country's chaotic currency situation. After the Gulf War, Iraq replaced the old "Swiss" dinars (as they were known because they were printed in Switzerland) with "Saddam" dinars, and then printed ever larger quantities to make up for the government's chronic budget shortfalls. Though the government maintained the official exchange rate of Saddam dinars at 0.3 to the dollar, the black market exchange rate reached 2,000 to the dollar by the time Coalition Forces attacked Iraq. By the end of April 2003, their value is around 3,000 to the dollar.

Although not printed since 1990, the older, "Swiss" dinars continue to circulate in the autonomous Kurdish regions of northern Iraq. Most are ragged, sometimes held together with tape, and there is no central bank that controls their supply—they simply re-circulate in the regions (Andrews, 2003). Through March 2003 and into early April of this year, speculative buying had doubled the dollar value of these "Swiss" dinars.

U.S. Treasury officials are in the process of assessing the possibilities for printing new batches of the Swiss dinars in either Iraq or abroad. Although Iraq did have printing and engraving plants, officials say they do not yet know how many of them are still functional or whether they can produce bills with modern anti-counterfeiting features like holograms (Andrews, 2003).

Until a new system is established, the dollar will also be an "official" currency. The dollar has circulated widely in Iraq for years. By some estimates, Treasury officials say, as much as $500 million may have been circulating before the war. Small denomination dollars notes will be put into circulation through "emergency" payments to hundreds of thousands of Iraqi civil servants in an effort to quiet civic unrest and to stabilize the economy (Associated Press, 2003).

American officials are working with finance and postal ministry officials from Saddam Hussein's government to figure out appropriate wages. Under the Hussein regime, the central government tightly controlled wages and prices. Setting wages too high could worsen inflation that is already running at about 70% annually. At first, the Iraqi workers will be given $20 each in $1 and $5 bills. That is a large sum in Iraq, where a midlevel oil professional with a chemical degree used to make the equivalent of $50 a month.

Also with no central bank or functional commercial banking system, the U.S. Agency for International Development will begin offering loans of between $100 and $250,000 to individual entrepreneurs and to small to medium-sized businesses.

With no central bank or economic mechanisms to control the volume of dollars in circulation however, there is no assurance that inflation can be curbed, or resources allocated efficiently. Clearly, a top priority in reconstruction will have to be the establishment of a central bank that can oversee the country's monetary and financial system.

Possible Exchange Rate Regimes for Iraq

With the establishment of a central bank, the first issue at hand is whether it should immediately begin to issue its own currency. If it does, what are the policy options available? Which are superior? While a whole spectrum of flexible exchange rate systems are possible—managed flexible rates, gliding bands, adjustable pegs, etc.—given the dearth of financial and administrative expertise to properly manage a flexible rate system this option can be immediately ruled out as providing the stability needed over the next decade or so for reconstruction, though they are certainly realistic alternatives after the country has developed a sound financial system and is integrated into the global economy. Given this reality, the discussion below will be confined to the relative advantages and disadvantages of possible fixed rate systems.

Currency Union: If Iraq opted for this option, a foreign currency would act as legal tender. Monetary policy would simply be delegated to the anchor (country of currency origin); the currency that circulates domestically would be literally the same as that circulating in one of the major economies, probably the dollar or possibly the euro.

The motivation underlying this choice would be to get the maximum credibility for inflation-resistant monetary policy. Clearly maximum credibility derives from the fact that the country simply did not have a monetary policy because it lacked a currency to print. In technical terms it would largely eliminate the occurrence of a phenomenon that economists have dubbed the "time-inconsistency problem"—the fact that a government's incentive today to keep inflation low does not mean that a government will have the same incentive tomorrow. For example, one of the new political parties in Iraq may be elected on the promise that it will reduce inflation. After a few years in office, but before the next election, the party may begin to reconsider its original position. It will realize that it can probably gain additional political support if it increases the money supply to pay for extra social programs without directly taxing citizens. Moreover, inflation will not become apparent until after the elections.

The problem for the government is that over time people are not stupid. After the first bout of inflation, individuals will anticipate from the start the government's incentive to inflate before its term is over—the voters may never lower their inflation expectations. The problem is compounded when the government in power today may not be the government in power tomorrow. Consequently, any anti-inflation statements that a political party makes will not be believed. This is the essence of the time-inconsistency problem and why governments, in order to create a credible anti-inflation policy, may want to have an independent central bank that does not have the same incentives to inflate as do elected members of government. An independent central bank (or in this case the lack of a central bank) can make it more difficult if not impossible for current and future governments to change course on monetary policy.

Use of another country's currency would not be without its own set of problems. These fall in three main categories.

First, the optimal currency area literature suggests that real shocks (for example terms of trade shocks) are better accommodated through flexible exchange rates, and nominal shocks (for example money demand shocks) through fixed exchange rates. Iraq would no doubt experience greater external than internal shocks during most of the reconstruction process. Because the country has virtually no money markets, fluctuations in oil revenues would be buffeted by movements in the country's real exchange rate, if it had its own currency. Using the dollar, however, would force these adjustments on the domestic economy—less output, more unemployment.

Domestic economic contractions of this sort would be especially the case if Iraq's economy was not in the same phase of the business cycle as that of the country of currency origin. For example, a dramatic fall in oil prices would stimulate output and production in the United States perhaps to the point where monetary policy tightened to choke off excess demand. The subsequent increase in Iraqi interest rates would only accentuate the drop in aggregate demand in that country, thus compounding the severity of the oil price drop

Warner (2003) sums up this aspect of possible dollarization in Iraq:

The supply of dollars would be determined by the U.S., the interest rates would be determined by the U.S., and in effect Iraq's capacity to borrow would be determined by the U.S. It scarcely needs saying that what might be important to Iraq would not merit so much a mention at the monthly meetings of the Federal Reserve's Open Market Committee to determine monetary policy. The Cincinnati Cat Fish Company would get a better look than Iraq.

Second, there would be no seignorage revenues—the difference between the cost of printing money and the non-inflationary value of goods and services the authorities could purchase with the newly issued money. This can be a fairly sizeable amount. Studies have shown that this is likely to be at least twice the country's pre-dollarization monetary base (Schmitt-Grohe and Uribe, 2000), or in Iraq's case millions and millions of dollars over time. However, under the circumstance the authorities might be able to negotiate a seignorage sharing agreement with the United States whereby the U.S. compensated Iraq for its lost income.

Third, Iraq would lack the lender of last resort function—the ability of the central bank to discount commercial bank paper would be lost. In difficult times, commercial banks would not be able to build up their reserves by selling their assets at stable values to the central bank. Depending on its holdings of dollars/euros the fiscal authority (Ministry of Finance for example) might be able to perform the lender of last resort function, but this would not be assured. In short dollarization does not necessarily imply the loss of a lender of last resort, but simply the disappearance of one particular source of liquidity, namely central bank credit.

In sum, dollarization (or eurozation) would have the chief advantage of providing a stable monetary environment for the country to recover. The system would place few demands on the country's monetary authorities, allowing the central bank breathing space to upgrade its staff to the point (in a decade or so) where more sophisticated monetary management would be feasible. There would be costs, perhaps the highest being the political/psychological one of appearing to be a colony of the United States. This alone might rule out dollarization.

Currency Board: Under this system, Iraq would have its own "currency". But it would be constrained in managing that currency: (a) the dollar/"dinar" exchange rate would be fixed not just by policy, but by law; (B) a reserve requirement stipulating that each dollar/euro's worth of domestic currency is backed by a dollar/euro's worth of foreign reserves; and © a self-correcting balance of payments mechanism, in which a payments deficit automatically contracts the money supply, resulting in a contraction of spending. Like dollarization, a currency board can help to create a credible policy environment by removing from the monetary authorities the option of printing money to finance government deficits.

The first currency board was established by the British in Mauritius in 1849. The use of currency boards eventually spread to 70 British colonies. The purpose was to provide the colonies with a stable currency without the associated difficulty of issuing sterling notes and coins that were costly to replace if lost or destroyed. The colonies also benefited from this approach in that they could earn interest on the foreign currency assets being held in reserve. The use of currency boards peaked in the 1940s and declined thereafter. In the 1960s many newly independent African countries replaced their currency board with a central bank, and most other countries followed suit in the 1970s.

There is certainly precedent for this type of system in Iraq and in fact historically Iraq has used a system similar to that adopted by many of the former British colonies. When Iraq was part of the Ottoman Empire, a number of European currencies circulated alongside the Turkish pound. With the establishment of the British mandate after World War I, Iraq was incorporated into the Indian monetary system, which was operated by the British, and the rupee became the principal currency in circulation.

In 1931, the Iraq Currency Board was established in London for note issue and maintenance of reserves for the new Iraqi dinar. The currency board pursued a conservative monetary policy, maintaining very high reserves behind the dinar. The dinar was further strengthened by its link to the British pound. In 1947 the government-owned National Bank of Iraq was founded, and in 1949 the London-based currency board was abolished as the new bank assumed responsibility for the issuing of notes and the maintenance of reserves. The National Bank of Iraq continued the currency board's conservative monetary policy, maintaining 100 percent reserves behind outstanding domestic currency.

In more recent times, another Gulf country, the UAE, had considerable success with a currency board. This board was established in 1973 mainly for issuing the national currency, the Dirham, and defending its parity (which was set at 0.186621 grams of gold, and in terms of U.S. dollars it was 3.94737 Dirhams for one U.S. dollar, with a margin of fluctuation of plus or minus one percent).

Prior to the creation of the Currency Board, and from the time the Trucial States abandoned the Indian Gulf rupee in 1966, various regional currencies such as the Bahraini dinar and the Saiudi and Qatari/Dubai riyals had served as local currencies in one emirate or another. The board was given the authority not only to issue a common currency for the union, but also to exercise central banking functions over the commercial and banking sector (Khalifa, 1979, p. 63). As with the case of Iraq noted above the currency board was eventually fazed out for a more traditional central bank with the power to issue its own money, not necessarily backed up by foreign assets.

The introduction of currency board-like arrangements in Hong Kong (1983), Argentina (1991), Estonia (1992), Lithuania (1994), Bulgaria (1997), Bosnia (1998), Ecuador (2000) and El Salvador (2001) constitutes their resurgence in recent years. Clearly, however, the Argentine experience has forced a closer examination of the usefulness of this system. However, Hanke (2003) has noted that the main problem in Argentina was that the system was a "currency board-like" system and not a true currency board.

Currency boards are not a panacea, and while one could produce the stability required for Iraqi reconstruction it would unlikely succeed indefinitely without reforms to increase competitiveness. This was Argentina's downfall. Thus after an impressive start, the Argentine government failed to liberalize trade enough to sufficiently expand exports. They failed to change restrictive labor laws. They raised taxes above U.S. levels. The result was that Argentina was not enough of a contender to withstand external shocks, or count on future investor confidence (Schlaes, 2002).

The main advantage of the Currency Board over the Currency Union is largely that of political/national pride. However, on the assumption that over time the country's economic institutions develop and mature, the currency board might be a good transition to a more flexible exchange rate system more under control of the Iraqi authorities. Also on the plus side, the time inconsistency problem noted above would be reduced, but now subject to the perceived probability that the Board might be abandoned. As with the Currency Union, real exchange rate volatility would be diminished.

Monetary Union: A monetary union for Iraq would entail accepting a common currency issued by a common regional central bank. Presently, there are no current regional unions of this sort Iraq might join, although the GCC countries are in the process of forming a currency union—the completion date of which is tentatively set for 2010—too far in the future to be of assistance for the country's reconstruction. In any case, Iraq's membership in the GCC monetary union is quite problematical at this point. Iraq's population is considerably larger than that of any of the GCC countries, implying that that country might have considerable advantages in industrialization, thus being a threat to several existing GCC members, notably Saudi Arabia.

The benefits of a monetary union are similar to the first two systems examined above. It would also reduce the time inconsistency problem by requiring multinational agreement on policy. Real exchange rate volatility would also probably be reduced. For both, however, the result would be less certain than in the case of dollarization or a classic currency board. It would have all of the disadvantages associated with both systems.

Traditional Peg: This system would entail setting a fixed rate between the new Iraqi currency and either the dollar or the euro (or some index weighted by the two). The potential benefit is that the time inconsistency problem would be reduced through commitment to a verifiable target. The system is more flexible than the currency board in that a devaluation option would always be open, thus providing a potentially valuable policy tool in response to large shocks. The system would also reduce real exchange rate volatility. However, the ability to periodically change the exchange rate is also the system's most serious limitation, with the possibility of instability stemming from investor speculation over possible rate changes.

In addition, because the system would relax the fiscal constraint on the government expenditures (the dinar would no longer have a one-to-one backing of dollar/euro reserves), inflationary pressures might develop. In turn, these could lead to the so-called Dutch Disease effect (Looney, 1989), characterized by an overvalued foreign exchange rate limiting the ability of the country to develop broad based diversification into export markets. Through cheapening imports, the exchange rate would also limit import substitution industrialization for the large domestic market.

Finally, because of the increased uncertainty surrounding possible devaluations, the exchange rate would, from time-to-time become a target for speculative attacks, especially during periods of low reserves and or high external debt servicing commitments. In short the pegged rate would avoid real exchange rate volatility, but not necessarily persistent misalignments. The approach does not by itself place hard constraints on monetary and fiscal policy and thus provides only a partial solution against the time inconsistency problem. The credibility effects depend on accompanying institutional measures and the record of accomplishment. Here the authorities could gain considerable credence by introducing and successfully managing a oil revenue stabilization fund. Proper management of the fund would smooth out oil expenditures leading to reduced inflationary pressures and exchange rate issues: doubts about sustainability in the presence of full capital mobility.

Conclusions

The main considerations concerning possible monetary and exchange rate systems in Iraq are summarized in Figure 1. Considering the current disarray of the Iraqi economy, dollarization is likely to be the best system to initiate in the country. This system would provide stability while providing limited demands on the country's central bank and money managers.

No doubt, the political sensitivities of a new Iraqi government will soon dictate the initiation of a new Iraqi currency. Here, the currency board option appears to be the best currency/exchange rate alternative. The system would provide the country with price stability. It would also be consistent with the economy's gradual liberalization and integration into the world economy. Most importantly, such a system would also restore foreign confidence in the country's ability to provide a stable environment for investment. However, a currency board would probably not be optimal in the longer-term.

A country of Iraq's economic size will eventually grow to the point where a more flexible system would provide a better tool for macroeconomic management of the domestic economy. Still, the board would provide the Iraqi authorities with some breathing space until a new central bank had gathered the experience and expertise to introduce a more complex, flexible exchange rate system. At that point the country could move to a fixed exchange rate, linking the Iraqi dinar to the dollar/euro or some basket of the two.

To avoid an overvaluation of the dinar and possible Dutch Disease effects (Ebrahim-Zadeh, 2003), the country should simultaneously have a fiscal policy built around an oil stabilization fund (Barnett and Ossowski, 2003). In turn, the fund would be designed to smooth out as much as feasible fluctuations in oil revenues. Over time, successful management of the fund could contribute to the stability of the exchange rate and thus the country's completion of the reconstruction and restructuring of its economy.

For more insights into contemporary international security issues, see our Strategic Insights home page.

To have a new edition of Strategic Insights delivered to your inbox each quarter, please e-mail ccc@nps.edu with "Subscribe" in your subject line. Subscriptions are free, and your address will be used for no other purpose.

References

"Iraq's Currency Hodgepodge: Officials to Begin Payments Using U.S. Dollars, but Everything Else in Circulation will be Accepted," Associated Press, (April 16, 2003).

"Rebuilding Iraq" The Economist, April 17, 2003

"The Hard Path to New Nationhood," The Economist, April 17, 2003.

Andrews, Edmund L. "Iraq to Run of Dollars Till It Gets New Currency," New York Times, (April 18, 2003).

Barnett, Steven, and Rolando Ossowski, "What Goes Up…Why Oil Producing States Must Husband their Resources," Finance & Development, March 2003.

Davis, Bob, Chip Cummins and Simeon Kerr, "Dollars Are Sent to Iraq to Replace Dinars: Stopgap Move is Intended for Emergency Payments in Effort to Quiet Unrest," Wall Street Journal,, April 16, 2003

Davis, Bob and Hugh Pope "Numbers Crunch: Once an Economic Dynamo, Iraq is Now Financial Riddle—To Rebuild Nation, U.S. First Must Find Reliable Data," Wall Street Journal, April 9, 2003.

Duncan, Gary, "IMF Haze Obscures Iraq's Horizon," London Times, April 14, 2003

Ebrahim-zadej, Christine, "Dutch Disease: Too Much Wealth Managed Unwisely," Finance & Development, March 2003.

Greimel, Hans, "Iraq's Dire Banking Blues: With the Country's Entire Financial System in Tatters, a New Central Bank is Seen as a Top Priority," Ottawa Citizen, (April 22, 2003).

Hanke, Steve, "The Euro Could Help Iraq's Economic Recovery," Financial Times, April 16, 2003.

Jbili, Abdelali and Vitali Kramarenko, "Should MENA Countries Float or Peg?" Finance & Development, (March 2003).

Khalifa, Ali Mohammed, The United Arab Emirates: Unity in Fragmentation (Boulder Colorado: Westivew Press, 1970, p. 62.

Morris, Harvey, "Currency Stabilization a Priority for Iraq," Financial Times, April 8, 2002.

Looney, Robert E., "Oil Revenues and Viable Development: Impact of the Dutch Disease on Saudi Arabian Diversification Efforts," American-Arab Affairs (Winter 1988-89).

Schmitt-Grohe, Stephanie and Martin Uribe, Stabilization Policy and the Costs of Dollarization, Departmental Working Papers series, Rutgers University Dept of Economics (May 31, 2000)

Shlaes, Amity, "It is Dangerous to Elevate a Currency as a Political Emblem if the Need for Other Economic Reforms is Obscured," Jewish World Reviewm 2002.

Stelzer, Irwin M. "Forgive Them His Debts: How Much of Saddam's Financial Baggage Should the Iraqi People Have to Carry?" The Weekly Standard, April 21, 2003.

Vieth, Warren, "Teams Prepare to Jump-Start Iraq's Economy: The U.S. is Helping Lay the groundwork for a Wide Range of Monetary, Fiscal and Private Sector Reforms in the War-Ravaged Country," Los Angeles Times, April 12, 2003.

Warner, Jeremy, "Iraq's Dollarization," The Independent (London), April 18, 2003.

Contacts | Copyright/Accessibility | Privacy Policy | FOIA | Intranet Access

This is an official U.S. Navy website.

All information contained herein has been approved for release by the NPS Public Affairs Officer.

Page Last Updated: May 20, 2010 3:03:34 PM | Contact the Webmaster

Thanks Chief.

First for your service and secondly for your post!

God bless you.

  • Upvote 1
  • Downvote 2
Link to comment
Share on other sites

To me, the amount of IQD currently in circulation is one of the two key pieces that is missing in all of this. I have heard many figures but haven't seen anything official. I'm not sure if Scooter has found this information in his research or not but I believe he has been looking for it.

A week or two ago someone said the total amount of all money in circulation throughout the world is $60 Trillion USD. I don't know if this is true or not but if true it provides a guide for us about what's realistic with the RV and what is not.

I mentioned in several other threads that a few weeks ago the G-20 press release for the meeting that will be held this weekend said that they were:

To me, that tells us the amount the RV could be valued at when added to the amount that the IQD is currently now worth. That $5 trillion has to come from somewhere. The other countries aren't going to print that much money so where else would this fiscal expansion come from?

IF that's the case then the amount in circulation is key to determining the rate.

The other important factor to me is what type of deal does the US, China and Europe have in place with regard to the IQD they are holding. Will the $5 Trillion added in the fiscal expansion be applied to the amount that they will have in their reserves so the money is added to prop up the economy but it isn't put into actual circulation?

I have a lot of questions but not many answers about this. Hopefully Scooter or some other knowledgeable person can answer them.

A lot of that money in various Central Banks is Repo Agreements that the 2 countries have traded to bolster their Foreign Currency Accounts.. This is all fake Currency and will dry up when the Repo's are unwound.. ie... I will give you an IOU for 100 Mil Euros and you give me an IOU for a Bil Dinars... No money changes hands.... then later on the IOU

s are unwound or traded back...Still no currency changes hands ...only the Repo's!

Edited by Stevarino
Link to comment
Share on other sites

Is it true? Did the FED buy $5.5T IQD??? If they did buy dinar and anything close to that number it is a huge validation an RV is coming.

Ummmm maybe i am dumb to think this .... but does it really matter how much dinar is floating around..? Or how much somebody or someone has? i dont think it matters... i could be wrong though

Link to comment
Share on other sites

Ummmm maybe i am dumb to think this .... but does it really matter how much dinar is floating around..? Or how much somebody or someone has? i dont think it matters... i could be wrong though

Yes, it matters because the fewer dinars in circulation the more each of the dinars in circulation is worth. So, for example, if there are 10 trillion IQD the RV would be at a lower number than if there are 5 trillion IQD in circulation. The fewer dinars in circulation the more money we will make.

  • Upvote 2
Link to comment
Share on other sites

Is it our money or Iraq's? What was behind wanting to earn interest for Iraq? Do you think "W" knew all the time there would be an RV because that was always the plan? Thx

Yes...Look up the Bush family and see what Grandpa did...There isnt one war thats not over money...The bushs made alot in WWII on both sides....In Japan..... Mitzubizies(or how ever its spelled) made the ZEROs, now we buy there t.v.s............So everyone please donate to the men and women who servied that were going to make money off of...THANKS TO ALL....I will make you as happy as Im going to be....

Link to comment
Share on other sites

Guest
This topic is now closed to further replies.
 Share

  • Recently Browsing   0 members

    • No registered users viewing this page.
×
×
  • Create New...

Important Information

By using this site, you agree to our Terms of Use.